Home
Early Electrum
Coins of Croesus
Early Coinage

This site is meant to provide ordinary collectors of ancient coins with a basic guide to the earliest coins in the western world, namely the electrum issues of Ionia and Lydia, and the gold and silver coins of Croesus (Kroisos).

Early Electrum Coinage.

Most collectors of ancient coins are naturally interested in the early electrum issues of Ionia and Lydia. However, they are faced with the problem that there is no single comprehensive and up to date catalog of these types, due in part to the fact we still have very limited knowledge of exactly where and when they were struck so that a definitive study is not as yet possible. As a result ordinary collectors often see these coins as a bewildering confusion of unattributed types, and hence they hardly know where to start when trying to put together a meaningful collection of the period. Not surprisingly this is enough to discourage the interest of many collectors, particularly as even the smaller examples of these types are not exactly cheap.

Therefore, in order to give collectors a better overall understanding of these types and how they relate together I have taken the limited evidence that we do have to go on and put together some charts of images of the key early electrum issues, ordered in space and time, down to roughly the fall of Croesus. These charts can be found on the "Early Electrum Coins" page.

Ultimately of course the basic aim of the study of these early types is to determine when and where (and why) coinage was first introduced. I'm not going to try to answer these questions in detail here myself, but I hope that the data as presented here will help readers assess the various theories that have been put forward over the years, and to understand the problems still to be solved in this key area of research*.

I will say however that, taking the charts at face value, it would seem likely that coinage was introduced in two phases. Initially we have unfigured (or striated) staters from Samos and Ionia B (probably Miletus**), together with a limited range of associated fractions - 1/2 and 1/4 staters, plus the odd 1/8 stater^. Then after a short time it seems that a new series of denominations was introduced, based on the 1/3 stater, with fractions ranging down to 1/96 stater (and even 1/192 stater). Just where and when these new denominations originated is not clear, but they were soon incorporated into the striated series at Miletus and the issues of Samos, and as the smooth unfigured types they make up what seem to be the earliest regular issues of Ionia A (Ephesus?).

At Miletus it seems that for a time 1/2 staters were still issued alongside the new 1/3 and 1/6 staters, as they share punches with the new types, but we notice an interesting fact - although most of these 1/2 staters have three reverse punches, some feature only two punches^^. What does this mean? One possible interpretation is that the two-punch 1/2 staters represent the earliest issues of Miletus, and that the change to three punches was made in order to distinguish the 1/2 staters from the new 1/3 staters, which now appropriated the two-punch reverse. (At Samos there seems to have been less of a problem, although one early series mixed a 1/3 stater with very similar 1/2 and 1/4 staters, but after that the 1/3 stater was dropped and new fractional denominations were based on the 1/6th stater, which was easily distinguished from the earlier types).

In any case, and whatever may have been the exact sequence of events, after a while it is clear that the 1/2 and 1/4 stater fractions were discontinued everywhere, and the 1/3 stater (or in some areas the 1/6 stater) became the effective basis of the currency throughout Ionia - full staters were still issued, but except at Miletus these were probably struck mainly for prestige reasons, or perhaps in some cases as commemorative types.

So, where and when did the 1/3 stater types and their derivatives first appear?

It's hard to be sure, but most likely they were introduced when Lydia first started to produce its own coins, namely the lion-head types. These were evidently mostly "trites" and their fractions, based on a Lydian trite/drachm of 4.72 gm (reflecting perhaps a Lydian mina of 472 gm). Given the local dominance of Lydia, these new denominations soon replaced the 1/2 and 1/4 staters in Ionia and Samos#.

Given the progression of types outlined above, it is difficult to see how coinage could have started with the lion-head types in Lydia, as has often been assumed, as all the "Lydian" lion-head series were clearly based on the 1/3rd stater (including the putative Lydia C and D series, the rare full staters of those mints notwithstanding). In fact the earliest Lydian lion-heads would seem, on the basis of their general style (and as we now know, similar gold content), to be no earlier, and possibly a little later, than the "panther" face type of (probably) Miletus, which was hardly the first issue of Ionia . (In any case the Lydian types can hardly have been primary, as then the earliest Ionian types would presumably also have been based on the 1/3 stater from the start, rather than the 1/2 stater).

One thing we can say is that the introduction of the 1/3 stater and its fractions probably entrenched coinage (rather than bullion or other goods) as the basis of the money economy. The earlier 1/2 and 1/4 staters were still too large to be useful in everyday transactions for most people, but the smaller denominations of the 1/3 stater series could well have been used in the market, at least at the wholesale level, and would presumably have been more convenient for the clearance of debts by ordinary people at the retail level. (At this stage people would generally have run accounts with local shopkeepers and tradesmen, and money would probably have been used mainly for the periodic settlement of these accounts, rather than for individual purchases). Thus the need for a simpler method of retail debt clearance may well have been the reason for the introduction of the smaller coin denominations in the first place, which may in turn explain, as we have seen, the shift to the 1/3 stater

*  Although a project to produce just such a catalog, the "Catalogue of Archaic Electrum Coinage" (CAEC), is now underway. It is unclear however whether this new catalog will be anything more than an updated version of Weidauer, i.e, basically a compilation of current museum holdings, or whether it will include the large amount of new material that has appeared in the market in recent years.

For the present collectors have to make do with Michener's "Ancient Trade and Early Coinage" (ATEC), which is fairly comprehensive but somewhat out of date and rather speculative in many areas (and not easily accessible to most collectors).

** The actual origins of many of the types listed here are not known with certainty, so that mints are designated as Ionia A, Lydia B, and so on in the charts.

^ For examples of full, 1/2 and 1/4 staters from Samos see Triton VIII 438-441. Other examples from Samos and Miletus are shown in Linzalone's "Electrum and the Invention of Coinage", noting that Linz. 1009 and 1010 are actually 1/4 staters of Samos.

^^ For a two-punch 1/2 stater and the corresponding (punch-linked) full stater see Triton VIII-433 and Triton VII-242 (shown here as the top two coins of Ionia B in the "Basic Electrum Types" chart). Triton IX-941 is presumably a 1/4 stater from the same period. There seem to be no corresponding 1/3rd staters (although these are all rare types, and CNG 72-760 could be a 1/6 stater from this period, or immediately afterwards). For the same or similar coins see Linzalone 1026, 1018 & 1032. For another two-punch 1/2 stater and a linked full stater see the oddly styled Heritage NYINC Jan. 2013-21229 and Baldwin's 70-20.

# I would guess that that the earliest opposing lion-head types of "Lydia A" (attributed mostly to "Walwet") were inspired by the similar but much less common lion-head types assigned here to Ionia J, which is possibly a Lydian, or at least Lydian controlled, mint. These latter types presumably evolved from the later striated issues of Ionia B where opposing lion and human heads were engraved on the large size striated obverse die plates used for the earliest staters. These obverse dies could perhaps then be the ultimate model for the oversized obverse dies used for the later two-headed types of "Walwet".

In this context we should keep in mind the fact that similar punch styles suggest that Ionia A and Lydia A could in fact be the same mint. In any case Ionia A was possibly, as Karwiese has suggested, a Lydian controlled mint located perhaps in the citadel of Ephesus, rather than in Ephesus itself. Ephesus seems to have issued few coins in its own right in the early period, other than the walking bee types and perhaps also the rare "rough unfigured" types. (It's not clear whether the rough types were issued at Ionia A or Ephesus proper, although their somewhat different punch style perhaps suggests Ephesus, but either way it's clear they were soon superceded by the smooth unfigured types of Ionia A).

The first Gold and Silver Coinage.

By the middle of the 6th century B.C, and quite possibly earlier, the Lydians had mastered the technique of separating electrum into gold and silver, and it is usually thought that the world's first gold and silver coins were issued at Sardis in Lydia during the reign of Croesus (c.560-546)*. These coins, with the facing lion and bull foreparts on the obverse, were evidently issued in various denominations at various times, and in fact their production was probably continued by the Persians for some time after Cyrus the Great had conquered Lydia. Eventually they were replaced in the later 6th century by the gold daric and silver siglos of Darius featuring the sitting or running king.

Several writers, notably Berk, Naster and Nimchuk, have attempted to classify the various issues of the Croeseid types, with, implicitly at least, the ultimate aim of arranging them in time. The results of these efforts have been limited, but nonetheless it's fair to say that significant progress has been made in defining the various issues, at least in broad terms. Unfortunately the key literature on these types is not easily available to the average collector, and therefore I have put together a chart of images of the different issues, arranged in time, which can be found on the "The Coins of Croesus" page. This chart is based on the ideas of various writers, but ultimately it reflects my own assessment of the available evidence.

* It is not impossible that the first "Croeseid" issues may have actually preceded the reign of Croesus, but for present purposes we will adopt the conventional dating.

Appendix - The Introduction of Electrum Coinage.

For a clear and reasonably up-to-date discussion of the basic problems of the early electrum coinage see Velde's "On the Origin of Specie", which can be found in various forms on the internet via the usual search engines. (The most usable version is probably the pdf file from the Institut de hautes études internationale at Geneva). For a more general view of the origin and role of coinage readers should also familiarise themselves with the ongoing "chartalism" versus "metallism" debate (don't be put off by the academic terminology - it just means token or fiduciary money versus real-value money).

 More specifically, for the moment the most popular explanation of the introduction of electrum coinage, due originally to Wallace, is that electrum coins likely originated as a way of standardising the use of natural electrum as a means of exchange. As more or less pure materials, gold and silver could be simply exchanged by weight, and silver in particular had for centuries been the prime medium of exchange in the market, but the varying composition and hence uncertain value of natural electrum created obvious difficulties in using it as a medium of exchange.

A system of certification was then introduced (so Wallace suggested) by which electrum lumps of fixed weight but uncertain actual composition were stamped and issued by the state* at some defined nominal value (in terms of gold and silver bullion). But what value? In his initial exposition of this theory Wallace doesn't specify this but clearly he assumes that the certified lumps will be token coins, i.e, that they will be significantly overvalued against their real value (whatever that might be). Thus the actual composition of the alloy, and hence the intrinsic real value of the coins, is largely immaterial - all that counts is the issuer's guarantee of nominal value, presumably underwritten by a promise of redeemability, and certified by the stamping of the lumps.

This is of course basically an updated version of Sture Bolin's famous thesis that the debased electrum coins were essentially a state swindle, although in this new version the people were apparently supposed to knowingly accept and use them as credit tokens.

But would ordinary people have accepted such an advanced concept at this stage in the development of coinage? Possibly, although my impression is that overtly token coins were very much the exception rather than the rule in ancient coinage, particularly in the early stages (for the primary coinages in precious metal at any rate - at a somewhat later stage the secondary issues in bronze quickly became tokens in most places).

Because of this I incline to a variation on Wallace's theory. The earliest coins must surely have been intended to be valued in terms of gold and/or silver bullion, and the most obvious way to do this would have been to issue certified coins of electrum, tariffed at (more or less) their real value. So what would this value have been?

Some idea is suggested by the analysis of the gold and electrum objects found during the excavations of the temple of Artemis at Ephesus. The gold content of the electrum objects ranged from c. 50% to a little more than 90% (there were also some high purity gold objects with gold contents in the high 90's range).

But there were also some early Ionian electrum coins amongst the finds with gold contents mostly in the 60% or so range, which suggests that the electrum content of these and similar early Ionian coins had been adjusted to yield a gold content of about 2/3. This in turn suggests a theoretical gold/silver ratio in the coin alloy of perhaps 7/4 (63.6% gold), as this, together with an assumed gold to silver value ratio of 12:1, would imply convenient value ratios for electrum to silver of 8:1 and electrum to gold of 2:3.

(Around 600 or so BC the temple of Artemis at Ephesus assumed a gold to silver value ratio of 11 2/3, rather less than the well known figure of 13 1/3 known for the later 6th century. Combining 11 2/3 with an alloy ratio of 21/11 (65.6% gold) yields value ratios of 8:1 for electrum/silver and 24/35 for electrum/gold).

So much for Ionia. In Samos the situation was rather messier.

Here two examples of the earliest types of Samos (the unfigured types) have yielded gold content figures of 74 and 79%, consistent with natural electrum, rather than some modified alloy.

But if the earliest issues of Samos did use natural alloy the situation soon changed. We also have figures for the second round of issues from Samos (the pebbly types) which show a wide spread in the alloy composition, with the gold content ranging from c.80% (as for natural electrum) down to less than 50%. Clearly while some of these types may have used raw electrum, for the most part they were made of a diluted alloy, although with seemingly rather poor quality control.

Overall, the wide variation in the alloy at Samos suggests that the coins there soon became fiduciary tokens, although still retaining (perhaps) the value of the earliest natural alloy issues.

The Samos situation however seems to be exceptional and in general it seems that the earliest series of electrum coins in Ionia (and somewhat later in Mysia) were meant to be real value coins, using an alloy containing roughly 2/3 gold. 

After not too long however the situation changed significantly, and a second round of coins appeared, notably in Lydia, based on a gold content of c. 54%.

The reason for this change is unclear. An alloy with a gold content in the mid 50% range doesn't yield any neat valuation relative to bullion, so we have to suspect that these new coins were traded as tokens, with a value equal to the earlier real value issues, enforced by the primary issuers, namely Lydia.

Over time this dilution of the alloy continued, and we see for example a gold content of c. 41% for the framed lion types of Miletus(?) and 41-47% for Phanes deer types of Ephesus^ .  (Samos, it should be noted, ultimately took a different approach - judging from the general paucity of post pebbly types it seems that it eventually largely gave up issuing electrum coinage).

Now all this sounds reasonable at first sight, as it accounts for the generally diluted alloy of the coins, and overvaluation of the token coinage means that the variability of the natural alloy is no longer a problem.

There are however still a few problems with this version of Wallace's theory. Firstly, it seems that the coin metal (in Lydia for example) was actually made by combining refined gold and silver to produce a purely artificial electrum, possibly because the natural electrum had run out, but more likely to improve the control of the alloy's composition. But if you now have regular supplies of gold and silver, why go the trouble of making an artificial electrum - why not take the obvious step and produce gold and silver coins?

And finally, the prime mover in the introduction of electrum coinage is usually taken to be Lydia, which had, it is generally assumed, copious supplies of natural electrum, and hence a vested interest in utilising them. However, the earliest actual electrum coins seem to have been issued, not in Lydia, but in Samos and Miletus. Why? - we don't know, and our theory gives us no clue.

Clearly we have much to learn about the rise of the electrum coinage, but another question is why did it ultimately fail, or to put it another way, why did the gold and silver coinage take over? Without getting too specific, in general terms the problem may have been that ultimately people simply lost faith in the electrum coinage system, with its varying gold content and token value, and hence they tried, like the Samians, to avoid it wherever possible (by reverting to weighed bullion perhaps). In the end then it is not surprising that most coin issuers were forced to finally switch to a more convincing and overtly real value system, which meant, in practice, gold and silver coinage^^.

Nonetheless, despite the ultimate failure of the electrum coinage system, the electrum pieces were the first to have their value certified by stamping, and as such they became the first true coins, while gold and silver were still being exchanged as bullion.

Behind all this of course is an interesting further problem - what was the source or sources of the natural electrum in the first place (it now seems doubtful that the Pactolus river was the main source of the Lydian electrum), and who controlled those sources - i.e, who would benefit from utilising them. These basic questions are yet to be answered.

* It is possible that entities other than the traditional polis were responsible for the introduction of coinage. For example it has been suggested that coinage was used by wealthy merchants or populist tyrants to free up markets and trade, and hence wrest control of the economy from the domination of the aristocratic elites. On this theory electrum was used precisely because it was not favoured by the elites as a store of value or medium of exchange, and hence gave the ordinary people an alternative to the gold and silver "monopolised" (in this theory) by the elites. Just how much truth there is in this idea is hard to determine, but the spread of coinage would no doubt have benefited the "new men", i.e, those "merchants and bankers" whose wealth derived from trade and finance, rather than the land of the traditional aristocracy.

^ For more information on the composition of the alloy of the various types see Gitler et al, "XRF Analysis of Several Groups of Electrum Coins" in "White Gold - Studies in Early Electrum Coinage" ed. van Alfen & Wartenberg, ANS New York 2020 (available on-line).

^^ Nonetheless some northern Ionian and Mysian mints, such as Phokea and particularly Kyzikos, did persist successfully with electrum issues until the establishment of the Macedonian supremacy in the 4th century. It appears that while the gold content of these types may have declined somewhat over time, it seems to have been fairly stable in the short term, so that they could be traded internationally as real value coins.

Ross Glanfield

Sydney, Australia

November 2012.

N.B: Given the peculiarities of the various browsers, viewers may need to adjust the displayed text size for comfortable viewing.

Latest additions/revisions:

 4 Nov. '13:   Examples of two-punch 1/2 staters cited. 
  9 Jan. '15:  Discussion of introduction of 1/3 staters revised.  
30 Sep. '15: Discussion of reason for earliest coinage revised again.
23 Oct. '15:   Possible reason for switch to 1/3 staters noted. 
  4 Oct. '21:  Some recent gold content data incorporated.
 3 Nov. '21:   Northern J mint revised to note Artemision coin.
12 Apr. '22: Some revision of Basic Electrum Types chart.
  4 Oct. '22:  Introduction of 1/3 staters revised again.
  3 Apr. '24:  Discussion of earliest electrum coinage revised.
 26 Sep. '24:  Discussion of earliest electrum coinage revised again.

Contact me by email at: jrg4@bigpond.com
 

[Home] [Early Electrum] [Coins of Croesus]